Discover millions of ebooks, audiobooks, and so much more with a free trial

Only $11.99/month after trial. Cancel anytime.

Capital: Volumes One and Two
Capital: Volumes One and Two
Capital: Volumes One and Two
Ebook793 pages14 hours

Capital: Volumes One and Two

Rating: 3.5 out of 5 stars

3.5/5

()

Read preview

About this ebook

Few writers have had a more demonstrable impact on the development of  the modern world than has Karl Marx (1818-1883). Born in Trier into a  middle-class Jewish family in 1818, by the time of his death in London  in 1883, Marx claimed a growing international reputation.



Of central importance then and later was his book Das Kapital, or, as it is known to English readers, simply Capital. Volume One of Capital  was published in Paris in 1867 and is available as a separate Wordsworth eBook. This  was the only volume published during Marx’s lifetime and the only to  have come directly from his pen. Volume Two, which is contained in this eBook, was published in 1884, and was based on notes Marx  left, but written by his friend and collaborator, Friedrich Engels  (1820-1895).



Readers from the nineteenth century to the present have been captivated  by the unmistakable power and urgency of this classic of world  literature. Marx’s critique of the capitalist system is rife with big  themes: his theory of ‘surplus value’, his discussion of the  exploitation of the working class, and his forecast of class conflict on  a grand scale. Marx wrote with purpose. As he famously put it,  ‘Philosophers have previously tried to explain the world, our task is to  change it.’

LanguageEnglish
Release dateOct 1, 2013
ISBN9781848705630
Capital: Volumes One and Two
Author

Karl Marx

Karl Marx (1818-1883) was a German philosopher, historian, political theorist, journalist and revolutionary socialist. Born in Prussia, he received his doctorate in philosophy at the University of Jena in Germany and became an ardent follower of German philosopher Georg Wilhelm Friedrich Hegel. Marx was already producing political and social philosophic works when he met Friedrich Engels in Paris in 1844. The two became lifelong colleagues and soon collaborated on "The Communist Manifesto," which they published in London in 1848. Expelled from Belgium and Germany, Marx moved to London in 1849 where he continued organizing workers and produced (among other works) the foundational political document Das Kapital. A hugely influential and important political philosopher and social theorist, Marx died stateless in 1883 and was buried in Highgate Cemetery in London.

Read more from Karl Marx

Related to Capital

Related ebooks

Philosophy For You

View More

Related articles

Reviews for Capital

Rating: 3.64499998 out of 5 stars
3.5/5

100 ratings5 reviews

What did you think?

Tap to rate

Review must be at least 10 words

  • Rating: 3 out of 5 stars
    3/5
    This was one of many books I read as part of my education n economic history. In it Marx describes his economic point of view which, surprising to me at the time, agreed with Adam Smith on at least one point. They both shared the "labor theory of value" which simply put argues that the value or cost of an item is based on the amount of labor necessary to produce it. This was supplanted by the subjective theory of value in the nineteenth-century which argues that the value of any item is determined by the value the consumer is willing to place on it. This in turn is interrelated with the scarcity of the item. Beyond this similarity the views of Marx departed from those of Smith. I was not impressed with theses views on my first reading in college and subsequent reading reaffirmed the arbitrariness and contradictory nature of much of Marx's work.
  • Rating: 3 out of 5 stars
    3/5
    There are actually some pretty good, interesting and challenging ideas in what is arguably one of the most important works in history, yet it is far from perfect and there seem to be quite a few flaws, gaps, judgment calls, perhaps an over-emphasis on idealism while neglecting reality or pragmatism, which is what I always felt was its primary weakness. Still, simply to understand why the world changed so radically prior to 1900 through the present, this is the basic place to begin...
  • Rating: 3 out of 5 stars
    3/5
    An incredibly dense read, but so much is said about communism, so much propaganda has been heard. Here is the basic for the now defunct social and economic theory. Some of his ideas still live.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    Most of this book is dedicated to footnotes. For nearly every point he makes, he studiously supports it with extensive footnotes that almost require footnotes themselves. If you are having difficulty seeing the "logic" of his connections then you are not spending enough time with the footnotes. That is how he reveals his logic. You can disagree with his conclusions, but that's not the same thing as being "illogical". Personally, I think his central thesis is quite logical. Capitalism requires a person to sell his labor for less than the value of the product of his labor, otherwise the capitalistic enterprise cannot make a profit. Then he fills the gaps with his version of class struggle solidifying the inherent unfair relationship between employee and employer as the profit motive becomes so paramount. Illogical? No. It's a classic analysis of conflict of interest. Controversial? Of course. This book is extensive, but it's easier to understand if you think of it as a model of capitalism at his time in history rather than some declaration of eternal truth. Karl Marx himself knew that this book was not capable of seeing the full expanse of capitalism. That's why he intended on writing three more volumes. His best friend and patron, Fredrich Engels had two more published based on Marx's notes and research since he died too early to make the other volumes happen.
  • Rating: 4 out of 5 stars
    4/5
    I am stunned to learn that this... this "rigid scientific investigation" is the foundational idea that so dramatically affected recent world history. Marx makes a series of illogical leaps to build his theory of labor and capital, while claiming to follow the same scientific process used in chemistry and physics. As is frequently done in economic writing, he begins with one argument: "For simplicity's sake we shall henceforth account every kind of labour to be unskilled, simple labour; by this we do no more than save ourselves the trouble of making the reduction." But he never comes back to show how the real-world violation of that assumption affects the relative market for each class of labor. He does a moderately successful job of showing the economics of "value add" but then creates another logical gap in the process of allowing free market exchange for each laborer's portion. (To summarize the argument, someone gets more for something and it clearly isn't the laborer.) It was interesting to see the reference to Robinson Crusoe (a frequent event in economics.) The closest he comes to that dangerous border of reality is his admission that compulsory labor is less productive. That is the point where an enterprising student could ask "because of lack of incentive?" In his own chapter on "contradictions" he himself makes a critical mathematical error in showing who gets the surplus value from exchange. Again, a whole argument is built on this to show the disparity that faces the worker. He bases the low living wage provided to workers as being similar to the ancient societies that bought from provinces with money taxed from them. In "The Labour Process" he references that the "way to Hell is paved with good intentions." He also quotes Benjamin Franklin. Summary: Due to monopoly power, the capitalist benefits from labor's surplus value without contributing anything to the process. Asserted but not proven.

Book preview

Capital - Karl Marx

Karl Marx

Capital, Volume 2

translated by Ernest Untermann

with an Introduction

by Mark G. Spencer

WORDSWORTH CLASSICS

OF WORLD LITERATURE

Capital first published

by Wordsworth Editions Limited in 2013

Published as an ePublication 2013

ISBN 978 1 84870 563 0

Introduction © Mark G. Spencer 2013

Wordsworth Editions Limited

8B East Street, Ware, Hertfordshire SG12 9HJ

Wordsworth® is a registered trademark of

Wordsworth Editions Limited

Wordsworth Editions is

the company founded in 1987 by

MICHAEL TRAYLER

All rights reserved. This publication may not be reproduced, distributed, or transmitted in any form or by any means, or stored in a database or retrieval system, without the prior written permission of the publishers.

Readers interested in other titles from Wordsworth Editions are invited to visit our website at

www.wordsworth-editions.com

For our latest list of printed books, and a full mail-order service contact

Bibliophile Books, Unit 5 Datapoint,

South Crescent, London E16 4TL

Tel: +44 020 74 74 24 74

Fax: +44 020 74 74 85 89

orders@bibliophilebooks.com

www.bibliophilebooks.com

For my husband

ANTHONY JOHN RANSON

with love from your wife, the publisher

Eternally grateful for your

unconditional love

Contents

Volume 2. The Circulation of Capital

Preface

Translator’s Note

Part 1: The Metamorphoses of Capital and Their Cycles

Chapter 1: The Circulation of Money-Capital

Section 1. First Stage. MC.

Section 2. Second Stage. Functions of Productive Capital

Section 3. Third Stage. C’M’.

Section 4. The Rotation as a Whole.

Chapter 2: The Rotation of Productive Capital

Section 1. Simple Reproduction.

Section 2. Accumulation and Reproduction on an Enlarged Scale.

Section 3. Accumulation of Money.

Section 4. Reserve Funds.

Chapter 3: The Circulation of Commodity-Capital

Chapter 4: The Three Diagrams of the Process of Circulation

Chapter 5: The Time of Circulation

Chapter 6: The Expenses of Circulation

Section 1. Genuine Expenses of Circulation.

Section 2. Expenses of Storage.

Section 3. Expenses of Transportation.

Part 2: The Turn-Over of Capital

Chapter 7: The Period and Number of Turn-Overs

Chapter 8: Fixed Capital and Circulating Capital

Section 1. Distinctions of Form.

Section 2. Composition, Reproduction, Repair, and Accumulation of Fixed Capital.

Chapter 9: The Total Turn-Over of Advanced Capital. Cycles of Turn-Over.

Chapter 10: Theories of Fixed and Circulating Capital. The Physiocrats and Adam Smith.

Chapter 11: Theories of Fixed and Circulating Capital: Ricardo

Chapter 12: The Working Period

Chapter 13: The Time of Production

Chapter 14: The Time of Circulation

Chapter 15: Influence of the Time of Circulation on the Magnitude of an Advance of Capital

Section 1. The Working Period Equal to the Period of Circulation.

Section 2. The Working Period Greater Than the Period of Circulation.

Section 3. The Working Period Smaller Than The Circulation Period.

Section 4. Conclusions.

Section 5. The Effect of a Change of Prices.

Chapter 16: The Turn-Over of the Variable Capital.

Section 1. The Annual Rate of Surplus-Value.

Section 2. The Turn-Over of the Individual Variable Capital.

Section 3. The Turn-Over of the Variable Capital, Considered from the Point of View of Society.

Chapter 17: The Circulation of Surplus-Value

Section 1. Simple Reproduction.

Section 2. Accumulation and Reproduction on an Enlarged Scale.

Part 3: The Reproduction and Circulation of the Aggregate Social Capital

Chapter 18: Introduction

Section 1. The Object of the Analysis.

Section 2. The Role of Money-Capital.

Chapter 19: Former Discussions of the Subject

Section 1. The Physiocrats.

Section 2. Adam Smith.

Section 3. The Economists after Smith.

Chapter 20: Simple Reproduction

Section 1. The Formulation of the Question.

Section 2. The Two Departments of Social Production.

Section 3. The Transactions between the Two Departments.

Section 4. Transactions within Department II. Necessities of Life and Articles of Luxury.

Section 5. The Promotion of the Transactions by the Circulation of Money.

Section 6. The Constant Capital of Department I.

Section 7. Variable Capital and Surplus-Value in Both Departments.

Section 8. The Constant Capital in Both Departments.

Section 9. A Retrospect on Adam Smith, Storch, and Ramsay.

Section 10. Capital and Revenue: Variable Capital and Wages.

Section 11. Reproduction of the Fixed Capital.

Section 12. The Reproduction of the Money Supply.

Section 13. Destutt de Tracy’s Theory of Reproduction.

Chapter 21: Accumulation and Reproduction on an Enlarged Scale

Section 1. Accumulation in Department I.

Section 2. Accumulation in Department II.

Section 3. Diagrammatic Presentation of Accumulation.

Section 4. Concluding Remarks.

Notes to Volume 2

Introduction

for T. R. Sansom

Few writers have had a more notable impact on the modern world than has Karl Marx (1818–1883). And much of Marx’s impact can be traced to Das Kapital: Kritik der politischen Oekonomie, or, as it is best known to its English readers, simply Capital. Marx’s Capital and Darwin’s Origin of the Species are often mentioned together as the two most influential books of the nineteenth century. Darwin’s principal works are still in print and Capital can still be published in the twenty-first century in a prominent series celebrating classics of world literature. Both are still relevant, but initially neither was welcomed. When the first volume of Capital was finally published in 1867 (in German), the forty-nine-year-old Marx had labored over it for such a long time that he felt compelled to offer an apology in the opening line of his preface: ‘The work, the first volume of which I now submit to the public,’ wrote Marx, ‘forms the continuation of my Zur Kritik der Politischen Oekonomie [A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy] published in 1859. The long pause between the first part and the continuation is due to an illness of many years’ duration that again and again interrupted my work.’ What he did not say is that his ill health was largely rooted in what had become for Marx, and his family, a life in exile full of uncertainty, disappointment, and recurrent poverty. He also does not say, but could have, that Capital came out of a much wider historical and intellectual context or that it had a much longer gestation period than Marx there lets on. When he wrote in 1867, Marx did not know that Capital’s immediate reception would be no more promising than its painstaking birth had been. Nor, of course, could he have known that his book would become one of the most acclaimed publications of the modern world.

Karl Heinrich Marx was himself born on 5 May 1818 in the ancient city of Trèves (or Trier) in the Mosel valley, a dependency of the Kingdom of Prussia (in a region that is a part of present-day Germany). His parents, Heinrich Marx (1777–1838) and Henrietta (née Pressburg, 1788–1863), provided him and his siblings (there were nine children in all) with a seemingly amicable middle-class upbringing which was in many respects not notable. One event that stands out from Marx’s youth is noted by all of his biographers, some reading more into it than others. That is the conversion of Marx’s father, a counselor-at-law to the High Court of Appeal, from Judaism to Protestantism in 1824 in order to help advance his career in the wake of anti-Jewish laws which were in effect. For some historians that event – and the unsettled station the young Marx, as a result of his Jewish background, may have felt – possibly explains some of Marx’s later antipathy (called by some, ‘self-hatred’) towards Judaism in particular and religion (‘the opiate of the masses’) in general.

Marx’s father left other imprints on his son. Heinrich was an avid reader; something that marked Karl from an early age. Along with reading from his father’s collection of books, which included many works of the French rationalists of the eighteenth century, Marx also regularly pillaged the library of a close family friend, Ludwig von Westphalen (1770–1842). Westphalen became a senior reading companion of the young Marx. He introduced the boy to works ranging from the epic poems of the ancient Greek writer Homer, to the tragedies and comedies of Shakespeare (1564–1616), and the utopian schemes of Claude Henri de Saint-Simon (1760–1825), to name a few which, many years later, would surface in the pages of Capital. This home-schooling, and then attendance at the local High School from 1830 to 1835, prepared Marx to enter university at age seventeen.

In October 1835, Marx enrolled at Bonn University as a student in the Faculty of Law. In his first year there he also entered into club life at the university and dabbled with writing verse, but met with little scholarly success. On more than one occasion, he also managed to get himself into trouble with the school authorities for offences such as ‘disturbing the peace of the night with drunken noise’. At the end of his first year, his father decided it was time for a change of location; in October 1836, Marx transferred to the University of Berlin. There, he continued to be interested in poetry and even more interested in writing verses for Jenny von Westphalen (1814–1881), Ludwig Westphalen’s beautiful daughter, to whom Marx had become secretly engaged. His formal preparation for the law included quite wide reading in history and philosophy, studies which he would draw upon later in his wide-ranging writings. At Berlin, his studies also began to take on a more serious edge. Like any student then his reading encompassed many of the ancients (Aristotle was a favorite), but also the writers of the Enlightenment, with an emphasis on those from France, German, and Scotland – including Voltaire (1694–1778), Jean-Jacques Rousseau (1712–1778), Paul-Henri Thiry, Baron d’Holbach (1723–1789), Adam Smith (1723–1790), Immanuel Kant (1724–1804), Johann Gottfried von Herder (1744–1803), Johann Wolfgang von Goethe (1749–1832), and Friedrich Schiller (1759–1805). Marx also read their critics. The most important of those was the recently deceased star of German intellectual life, the philosopher Georg Wilhelm Friedrich Hegel (1770–1831), who had held the Chair of Philosophy at Berlin. Hegel’s conception of history as a process that progressed dialectically was to stay with Marx even as he came to question other aspects of Hegel’s thought. And perhaps just as important for explaining the development of Marx’s thought at this time was the company he kept.

At the University of Berlin, Marx, like many other German students of his generation, was introduced to the possibility of applying Hegel’s theory of the dialectic to the real world, not only to understand the past but to achieve revolutionary change in the future. Marx’s professors at the university included the conservative Friedrich Karl von Savigny (1779–1861) but, more importantly for the lesson mentioned above, Eduard Gans (1797–1838). Mixing with Gans and others who considered themselves to be the ‘Young Hegelians’, Marx became intimate with radical thought and its implications. Among his closest acquaintances at this time were Adolph Rutenberg (1808–1869) and the Bauer brothers – Bruno (1809–1882), Edgar (1820–1886), and Egbert – one of whom (Edgar) commented in verse on Marx’s activities in the club:

But who advances here full of impetuosity?

It is a dark form from Trier, an unleashed monster,

With self-assured step he hammers the ground with his heels

And raises his arms in full fury to heaven

As though he wished to seize the celestial vault and lower it to earth.

In rage he continually deals his redoubtable fist,

As if a thousand devils were gripping his hair.

However, Marx’s letters home to his father during these years strike a far less self-assured tone and show him to have been searching for philosophical direction at the same time that he was finding himself as a young man. His father, like many fathers since, strongly preferred that his son drop his flighty pursuits of philosophy and history for something more practical that would lead directly to a well-paid government job. He asked pointedly in a letter sent before his death in 1838, ‘And do you think that here in this workshop of senseless and aimless learning, you can ripen the fruits to bring you and your loved one happiness?’ After his father’s death, it did not take Marx long to give up any pretense of studying law. By January of 1839 he had begun work on his doctoral dissertation, ‘The Difference between the Philosophies of Nature in Democritus and Epicurus’. Had his father been alive to see it, he would not have been pleased. In April 1841, Marx submitted (by post) his thesis to the University of Jena and was awarded his degree in absentia.

Aspiring at first to a university appointment, Marx settled in the immediate term for work as a journalist. His first article was published in May 1843 in the Rheinische Zeitung, a newspaper published in Col-ogne and headed by Moses Hess (1812–1875), the so-called ‘Communist Rabbi’ who was the author of The Sacred History of Mankind (1817). From October 1842, Marx edited that paper. Only a few years older than Marx, Hess had quickly become infatuated with Marx’s philosophical prowess. Hess wrote of the twenty-four-year-old Marx: ‘He is the greatest, perhaps the one genuine philosopher now alive . . . Dr Marx . . . combines the deepest philosophical seriousness with the most biting wit. Imagine Rousseau, Voltaire, Holbach, Lessing, Heine and Hegel fused into one person – I say fused, not thrown together in a heap – and you have Dr Marx.’ Under Marx’s guidance the content of the Rheinische Zeitung took a decidedly radical turn and its circulation and reputation increased significantly. This notoriety probably ended any chance Marx had for a university position. Moreover, the Prussian government moved to shut down the newspaper in early 1843. Marx resigned his editorship in March.

Looking back at these years, Marx commented in his ‘Preface’ to A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy (1859), that it was as editor of the Rheinische Zeitung that he ‘experienced for the first time the embarrassment of having to take part in discussions on so-called material interests [which] . . . provided the first occasion for occupying myself with economic questions.’ As Vladimir Ilyich Lenin (1870–1924) put it in his biographical sketch of Marx, ‘Marx’s journalistic activities convinced him that he was insufficiently acquainted with political economy, and he zealously set out to study it.’ Applying his stock of knowledge to the close study of real-world questions of local concern may also have offered Marx the first glimpse of the power of intellectuals to bring about revolutionary change:

The system of profit and commerce, of property and human exploitation, leads much more quickly than an increase of population to a rift inside contemporary society that the old society is incapable of healing, because it never heals or creates, but only exists and enjoys. The existence of a suffering humanity which thinks and a thinking humanity which is oppressed must of necessity be disagreeable and unacceptable for the animal world of philistines who neither act nor think but merely enjoy.

For Marx, it was the self-assigned task of the intellectual to assure that ‘the old world . . . [is] brought right out into the light of day and the new one given a positive form. The longer that events allow thinking humanity time to recollect itself and suffering humanity time to assemble itself the more perfect will be the birth of the product that the present carries in its womb.’ Or, as he put it elsewhere:

The weapon of criticism cannot, of course, replace criticism by weapons, material force must be overthrown by material force; but theory also becomes a material force as soon as it has gripped the masses. Theory is capable of gripping the masses as soon as it demonstrates ad hominem, and it demonstrates ad hominem as soon as it becomes radical.

The world of radical newspaper writers was always to be the place where Marx felt most at home.

The year 1843 was an important one for Marx. In the early spring of 1843, having resigned from the Rheinische Zeitung, Marx sought gainful employment in other ways. That became even more pressing when, in April, Marx and Jenny Westphalen were finally married after an exceedingly long engagement. Jenny would be his life-long companion; ‘infinitely mercurial’ in good times, and in bad. Together they would have six children, although only three would survive to adulthood. 1843 was also the year that Ludwig Feuerbach (1804–1872) published his Preliminary Theses on the Reformation of Philosophy, a book that Marx devoured with lasting effect. Isaiah Berlin (1909–1997), the historian of ideas, described Feuerbach’s impact on Marx in this way: ‘Feuerbach is one of those interesting authors, not infrequently met with in the history of thought, who, without being thinkers of the first order, nevertheless provide men of greater gifts with the sudden spark which sets on fire long-accumulated fuel.’ But Feuerbach was not the only one whom Marx read in 1843. That year he began a period of intense study of political philosophy, reading Machiavelli’s The Prince (1532), Montesquieu’s Spirit of the Laws (1748), Rousseau’s Social Contract (1762), and Adam Smith’s An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (1776). They were all read or re-read as Marx worked out a Critique of Hegel’s ‘Philosophy of Right’ and took manuscript notes that would later inform parts of Capital. Finally, 1843 was also the year that Marx decided to leave Prussia for Paris, a city that was then the gathering point for Europe’s radical intellectuals. In October 1843, as this eventful year drew to a close, Marx and his pregnant bride made their way to France where Marx helped Arnold Ruge (1802–1880), another political exile who had been one of the ‘Young Hegelians’, to edit the short-lived Deutsche-französische Jahrbücher [German-French Annals]. Working closely together, Marx and Ruge came to see they differed considerably in their understanding of socialist theories. With another contributor to the Deutsche-französische Jahrbücher Marx shared much more. This man would become Marx’s most intimate of friends and most important of collaborators – Friedrich Engels (1820–1895).

Marx and Engels had met briefly in Prussia, in November of 1842, in the office of the Rheinische Zeitung. Looking back at their reunion in August 1844 in Paris at the Café de la Régence, Engels recorded that ‘When I visited Marx in Paris in the summer of 1844, we found ourselves in complete agreement on questions of theory and our collaboration began at that time.’ At the time, Engels was working on a project which aimed to describe and criticize the lives of the industrial poor in Manchester, England, and to suggest ways they might be improved. The expanding industrial world of nineteenth-century Europe was one that Engels knew well. He was an industrial insider since his wealthy family had business interests not only in Manchester but also in the Rhineland at Barmen (near Dusseldorf), a town that became known as the ‘Little Manchester’. Engels’s project, The Condition of the Working Classes in England, was first published in Leipzig in 1845.

The intellectual team of Marx and Engels has been considered by some to represent a merging of the theoretical mind of Marx with the empirical and practical mind of Engels. But that way of seeing things may not give sufficient weight to the empirical side of Marx which appears to have been with him from the beginning. When commenting on their collaboration, Engels always cast himself as the lesser of the two, later writing that

Marx could very well have done without me. What Marx accomplished I would not have achieved. Marx stood higher, saw farther, and took a wider and quicker view than all the rest of us. Marx was genius; we others were at best talented. Without him the theory would not, by a long way, be what it is today. It therefore rightly bears his name.

In January 1845, as political tensions mounted throughout Europe and particularly in Paris, Marx was expelled from France. He made his way to Belgium which, like England was highly industrialized, and he and Jenny settled in Brussels. In 1846, Marx and Engels traveled to London together where they studied, talked, and wrote The German Ideology. That volume was not published until 1932, but it circulated as a manuscript in the nineteenth century and is a work that clearly articulated Marx’s historical materialism:

In direct contrast to German philosophy which descends from heaven to earth, here we ascend from earth to heaven. That is to say, we do not set out from what men say, imagine, conceive, nor from men as narrated, thought of, imagined, conceived, in order to arrive at men in the flesh. We set out from real, active men, and on the basis of their real life-process we demonstrate the development of the ideological reflexes and echoes of this life-process.

In The German Ideology, ‘communism’ was ‘an ideal to which reality will have to adjust itself . . . the real movement which abolishes the present state of things’. Marx had gradually drifted away from seeing philosophy – as the ‘Young Hegelians’ of his university years had, and continued to – as an intellectual endeavour. As Marx put it, ‘The philosophers have only interpreted the world, in various ways; the point is to change it.’

Part of what needed to be righted, Marx and Engels argued, was the modern tendency towards a strict division of labor:

In communist society, where nobody has one exclusive sphere of activity but each can become accomplished in any branch he wishes, society regulates the general production and thus makes it possible for me to do one thing today and another tomorrow, to hunt in the morning, fish in the afternoon, rear cattle in the evening, criticize after dinner, just as I have a mind, without ever becoming hunter, fisherman, cowboy or critic.

At the same time, Marx was coming to see more clearly how the division of labor not only alienated the worker from his work, but also the worker from himself. Adam Ferguson’s An Essay on the History of Civil Society (1767) and Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations (1776) were probably both in the background here. Smith was certainly not blind to the potentially negative moral consequences of market forces or the possibly devastating implications of the division of labor for individual labourers. As Smith had put it in the Wealth of Nations:

In the progress of the division of labour, the employment of the far greater part of those who live by labour, that is, of the great body of the people, comes to be confined to a few very simple operations; frequently to one or two. But the understandings of the greater part of men are necessarily formed by their ordinary employments. The man whose whole life is spent in performing a few simple operations, of which the effects too are, perhaps, always the same, or very nearly the same, has no occasion to exert his understanding, or to exercise his invention in finding out expedients for removing difficulties which never occur. He naturally loses, therefore the habit of such exertion, and generally becomes as stupid and ignorant as it is possible for a human creature to become.

Marx would come back to these themes in Capital, but that was still twenty years away.

In 1847, Marx published his La Misère de la Philosophie, an attack on Pierre-Joseph Proudhon (1809–1865), whose work Marx had once praised but now saw sorely lacking in historical content. What he kept was the idea that property was theft – of labour, time and life. Marx also set to work on his Theses on Feuerbach. He paid his bills and fed his family with donations from Engels. That would be a recurrent fact in their lives. It was also at this time that Marx’s materialist conception of history came into sharper focus. For Marx, ‘politics and its history have to be explained from the economic conditions and their evolution and not vice versa.’ Again, Adam Smith and other Scots, such as David Hume (1711–1776), had been there first with their idea that consciousness was formed by work and that laws reflected economic conditions, as John Millar (1735–1801) had also argued.

Marx and Engels were becoming increasingly involved in revolutionary circles, even taking on organizational roles. That was the case in early 1847 when they were involved with the formation of a clandestine international political party that became known as the Communist League. In late 1847 and early 1848, encouraged by a group of German émigrés residing in London, Marx and Engels worked together to write for this party The Communist Manifesto, the most widely-read of all of Marx’s literary productions. ‘The history of all hitherto existing society,’ Marx and Engels wrote, ‘is the history of class struggle.’ ‘A spectre is haunting Europe – the spectre of communism.’ By the middle of 1848, with revolution sweeping across Europe, Marx and his growing family moved to Cologne. Joined by Engels, the two men brought back to life a revamped Rheinische Zeitung as the Neue Rheinische Zeitung, the so-called ‘Organ of Democracy’. The future must have looked potentially bright for Marx. But things were soon to change. Within a year, revolutionary regimes were failing around him and his newspaper was forced to close. Once again Marx was forced into exile; this time it involved travel by ship to England.

When he sailed to London in August 1849, Marx could not have known how bleak the next decade would be for him and his family. He would later refer to these years as his ‘sleepless night of exile’. The 1850s began with some promise of success, personal and professional. Marx brought to the press The Class Struggles in France (1850) and The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Bonaparte (1851), a work in which Marx used Louis Bonaparte’s dictatorship as Emperor Napoleon III to comment on the relationship between social classes, politics, and history. Even the failed 1848 revolutions Marx thought might be explained away as only a temporary setback which would, with time and changing social and political circumstances, give way to the inevitable march of history toward a revolution by the proletariat. The future, so to speak, looked bright and its realization was inevitable.

Historians are not agreed on the extent to which Marx and his family lived in poverty in the 1850s. However that is measured, life was not comfortable. Working as a free-lance journalist, as he was, provided some income, particularly when Marx was writing for the New York Daily Tribune. But there was not much security in that. Life in the Marx household in a cramped three-room Soho apartment on Dean Street was certainly very different from the bourgeois comforts of Marx’s youth. Jenny, who had long fretted about financial security, had written soon after their marriage:

Dear heart, I have too great an anxiety about our future, both in the long and the short term, and I think that I shall be punished for my present high spirits and exuberance. If you can, please calm my fears on this point. People talk far too much about a steady income. I then answer simply with my red cheeks, my white flesh, my velvet cloak, my feathered hat and my fine ribbons.

In the early 1850s, velvet cloaks and fine ribbons must indeed have seemed to Jenny only an extravagant memory of a distant past. Son Henry, born in 1849, had died in November 1850. A visitor to the household remarked: ‘Marx lives in one of the worst, therefore one of the cheapest quarters in London . . . In the whole apartment there is not one clean and solid piece of furniture. Everything is broken, tattered and torn, with a half inch of dust over everything and the greatest disorder everywhere.’ As David McLellan, one of Marx’s twentieth-century biographers, put it, during the 1850s the ‘pawnshop was an indispensable institution for the Marx household’. In September 1852, Marx himself lamented:

My wife is ill, little Jenny is ill, Lenchen has a sort of nervous fever, I cannot and could not call the doctor because I have no money for medicine. For 8–10 days I have fed the family on bread and potatoes of which it is still questionable whether I can rustle up any today . . . I have tried everything, but in vain . . . How can I get clear of all this hellish muck?

Born in early 1851, daughter Jenny (Franziska) had died by the spring of 1853. On 6 April 1856 tragedy struck yet again; Edgar, their only son, died, age 8. Four months later the loss was still palpable. Marx wrote to a friend, ‘The death of my child has deeply shaken my heart and mind and I still feel the loss as freshly as on the first day. My poor wife is also complete broken down.’ Still, work on Capital carried on, largely in the Reading Room of the British Library (possibly a hiding place from debt collectors), sometimes standing because of painful carbuncles, and always with a cigar close to hand. Marx once lamented to a friend that ‘Capital will not even pay for the cigars I smoked writing it.’ During the same years that Marx was working on what would be his masterpiece – in what we have seen to have been far from ideal circumstances – he contributed some 500 separate pieces to the New York Daily Tribune. As always, Marx could cast off pieces on daily affairs while working up timeless classics.

These were some of the various biographical, intellectual, and political contexts in which Capital was envisioned, sketched, and partly composed. In many ways Capital can be seen as an extension of Marx’s earlier collaborations with Engels and as a summary and expansion of Marx’s prior publications stretching all the way back to the earliest of them. Indeed, many of those earlier publications are referred to in Capital and even quoted or repeated verbatim. What we now consider Das Kapital is a book of three Volumes: Volume 1, The Process of Production of Capital; Volume 2, The Process of Circulation of Capital; and Volume 3, The Process of Capitalist Production as a Whole. Volume 1, first published on 14 September 1867, was the only volume that Marx saw through the press as it was the only part of Capital published during his lifetime. Marx left manuscript notes for Volume 2, but the volume was prepared by Engels and not published until 1885. Volume 3, also prepared by Engels, was not published until 1894.

Capital, taken as a whole, is a far-ranging book that is not easy to summarize. Jon Elster’s twentieth-century appraisal of Marx’s writing in general applies nicely to Capital: ‘Even in his most carefully written works, Marx’s intellectual energy was not matched by a comparable level of intellectual discipline. His intellectual profile is a complex blend of relentless search for truth, wishful thinking, and polemical intent.’ At its core, Capital is concerned with the capitalist mode of production, exchange, and distribution. Looking at the project as a whole, Marx’s aim was to pursue those themes, wherever they led, through the various realms of political economy, European history, and sociology. Marx was critical of capitalism because as a system of political economy it was inefficient; historically it was, and promised to continue to be, exploitative; and perhaps most importantly of all, it alienated the workers without whom it would fail. For Marx, ‘alienation’ has a technical meaning. James Russell provides a useful definition in his Marx-Engels Dictionary:

The separation of one or more humanly defining conditions for human beings. Marx specified two humanly defining conditions of human nature: humans are social beings, and they develop their societies and themselves through creative labour . . . The capitalist class owns and controls the means of production. Hence workers are separated (alienated) from control over how their work is planned, how the product is to be used, their interrelationships with other workers, and lastly themselves, since the capitalist directs them instead of allowing them to be creatively self-directed.

Volume 1 of Capital was intended ‘to discover the economic law of motion of modern society’. The table of contents for that volume provides something of a roadmap to Marx’s discussion of ‘The Process of Production of Capital’. There are 8 parts in all: Part 1, ‘Commodities and Money’; Part 2, ‘The Transformation of Money into Capital’; Part 3, ‘The Production of Absolute Surplus-Value’; Part 4, ‘The Production of Relative Surplus-Value’; Part 5, ‘The Production of Absolute and of Relative Surplus-Value’; Part 6, ‘Wages’; Part 7, ‘The Accumulation of Capital’; and Part 8, ‘The So-Called Primitive Accumulation’. Even with this roadmap, readers have not always found the book easy to follow.

On reading it in the nineteenth century, William Morris (1834–1896) recorded in a memorable passage that he ‘suffered agonies of confusion of the brain’. Jon Elster points out that while Marx wrote in part to motivate factory workers of the world, he frustratingly ‘assumes that his readers know Greek, Latin, and the major European languages; that they are capable of recognizing remote allusions to literary and philosophical works, besides being thoroughly familiar with arcane matters of political economy.’ Isaiah Berlin remarks quite simply with reference to Volume 1 of Capital, ‘Marx is not the clearest of writers.’ When modern students grapple with Capital they should take solace in the fact that they are not alone.

Few books have seen as many ‘Reading Guides’ published to help the lost, but persistent, navigate their way. For some, such as French philosopher Louis Althusser (1918–1990) for instance, part of the difficulty is that Capital is too much a work of theory. In Althusser’s case, Part 1 is so theoretical that he recommends readers at first skip it entirely, and only come back to it when they are armed with a firm knowledge of the rest of the book. Marx himself wrote in the ‘Preface’ to the first edition that ‘Beginnings are always difficult in all sciences. The understanding of the first chapter, especially the section that contains the analysis of commodities, will therefore present the greatest difficulty.’ But are there other ways to approach the text that differ from what Althusser recommends?

What unites Capital is Marx’s overarching sensitivity to the consequences of the science of political economy for the lives of real human beings. Despite the book’s theoretical span and historical range, the frame of reference is always a human one. For instance, consider the very first page where Marx introduces ‘commodities’. The book begins: ‘The wealth of those societies in which the capitalist mode of production prevails, presents itself as an immense accumulation of commodities; its unit being a single commodity.’ Theoretical, perhaps; but the opening paragraphs also explain that while a commodity is an ‘object outside us’ it is something that ‘satisfies human wants of some sort or another’. Those wants might arise ‘from the stomach or from fancy’; from which ‘makes no difference’.

It is worth noting that this is an aspect of Capital that unites it with Marx’s earlier writings. As Erich Fromm has argued in his volume on Marx’s Concept of Man, ‘Marx is primarily concerned with the emancipation of man as an individual.’ When interviewed by his daughters in the Victorian parlour game known as ‘Confessions’, Mark answered the question, ‘What is your Favourite Maxim?’ with the simple answer: ‘Nihil humani a me alienum puto.’ [‘I regard nothing human as alien to me.’] This aspect of Capital is also something that unites it with the political economy of the Scottish Enlightenment from which Marx drew heavily. Many years ago the historian of economics Ronald L. Meek argued for the impact of what he referred to as the ‘Scottish Historical School’ on Marx. Meek had in mind Adam Smith, Adam Ferguson and James Millar, all mentioned above, but also William Robertson (1721–1793), Lord Kames (1696–1782), Gilbert Stuart (1742–1786), Lord Monboddo (1714–1799), Hugh Blair (1718–1800) and James Dunbar (1742–1798). For these Scots in the eighteenth century, as for Marx in the nineteenth, there are systems to be built when we attempt to understand economic and political man, but all of them focus on individuals in society. Meek claimed that ‘Smith, like Marx, was a whole man, who tried to combine a theory of history, a theory of ethics, and a theory of political economy into one great general theoretical system.’ When Capital is approached in this way – with a focus on the human dimension – some of its passage become easier. Illustrative of this possibility, recently Volume 1 has even been recast as a best-selling Japanese comic book! In Capital in Manga! we find the ‘story of a cheese-maker turned capitalist and how greed, exploitation and its social consequences destroys lives and remakes workers into commodities.’ As the Canadian publishers of the English translation put it on the back cover, ‘As the gap between the rich and poor continues to widen, a new generation is once again reflecting on Karl Marx’s revolutionary insights . . . It is hoped that this Manga may act as a bridge to Marx’s original work . . . Marx not only stood against the global economic system but he also helped us understand it.’

It is worth remembering, as well, that for all of the commentary on Capital as a scientific work, Marx referred to it more than once as a ‘work of art’. As Francis Wheen and others before him – such as S. S. Prawer – have pointed out, to overlook the literary aspects of Volume 1 is to overlook too much. It ought to be ‘read as a work of the imagination: a Victorian melodrama, or a vast Gothic novel whose heroes enslaved and consumed the monster they created (Capital which comes into the world soiled with mire from top to toe and oozing blood from every pore); or perhaps a satirical utopia like Swift’s land of the Houyhnhnms, where every prospect pleases and only man is vile.’ Some of the most entertaining passages are found in Marx’s caustic footnotes.

The initial muted reception of Volume 1 of Capital did not give Marx much cause for celebration, or hope. He wrote to Engels in October, ‘The silence about my book makes me fidgety.’ If possible, Jenny was even more frustrated than was her husband by the lack of public attention: ‘There can be few books that have been written in more difficult circumstances, and I am sure I could write a secret history of it which would tell of many, extremely many unspoken troubles and anxieties and torments. If the workers had an inkling of the sacrifices that were necessary for this work, which was written only for them and for their sakes, to be completed they would perhaps show a little more interest.’ Eventually reviews appeared – even some that had not been planted by Engels – but Marx’s pamphlet of 1871, The Civil War in France, drew more attention than had the first volume of his masterpiece. In the wake of that uproar, Marx published a second edition of Volume 1 of Capital in the winter of 1872/3.

Marx continued to work on the manuscripts of Volumes 2 and 3, but progress was slow as the philosopher’s rough life began to show in his aging body. Good health was in short supply; he was under doctor’s orders to forgo his habit of working in the evenings, and serious scholarly pursuits increasingly gave way to more relaxed pastimes, such as playing with and reading to his growing number of grandchildren. Jenny, too, had not been well and sensed her end was near. She died on 2 December 1881. Marx’s health was so poor at the time he was unable to attend her funeral or burial at London’s Highgate Cemetery. In January 1883 Jenny Marx Longuet, the Marxs’ eldest daughter, died, probably of bladder cancer. Marx’s health went from bad to worse although he hung on to life until 14 March 1883, when he died at age 64. On 17 March, without much fanfare or even notice, he was buried alongside Jenny in Highgate Cemetery. His life-long friend, Engels, delivered a short eulogy which concluded: ‘His name will endure through the ages, and so also will his work!’ Fewer than a dozen were in attendance.

Engels inherited his friend’s notes and manuscripts and from those completed Volume 2 of Capital, the first German edition of which was published in July 1885. Below, readers will find reprinted the complete text of Volume 2, The Process of Circulation of Capital. Engels explained in his Preface to that volume that, ‘It was no easy task to prepare the second volume of Capital for the printer in such a way that it should make a connected and complete work and represent exclusively the ideas of its author, not of its publisher.’ Volume 2 is divided into three parts: Part One, ‘The Metamorphoses of Capital and their Cycles’; Part Two, ‘The Turn-Over of Capital’; and Part Three, ‘The Reproduction and Circulation of the Aggregate Social Capital’. The second volume is very different from the first. Gone, almost entirely, are the literary allusions and playful footnotes. Marx was a writer of genius, but from the manuscript he left of the second volume of Capital it was impossible for Engels to match the first volume. Despite its notable deficiencies, it is useful to include here to provide the reader with a fuller sense of what the project as a whole contained.

In 1887 the first English translation of Volume 1 of Capital appeared in London, published by Swan Sonnenschein, Lowrey & Co, on Paternoster Square. Edited by Engels, the translation was prepared by Samuel Moore and Edward Aveling (1849–1898), Eleanor Marx’s partner. That is the text reprinted below. Volume 3 of Capital, also prepared by Engels, was first published in 1894. As Jon Elster noted, the modern consensus is that the economic theories espoused in Volume 3 are ‘seriously flawed’ and ‘the non-specialist reader will not profit much from struggling with Marx’s exposition of them.’ Volume 3 is not reprinted below.

As with all authors of literary classics, Marx’s reputation changes with the times. The reception of Marx and Capital has ebbed and flowed with the subsequent course of history. Little celebrated at the time of his death in 1883, by 1917 Marx was seen as the intellectual hero of the Russian Revolution. Since then, Marx’s reputation has risen, and fallen, along with the fates of Marxist regimes around the world and with events like the Great Depression which made many Marxists in both America and Europe. In recent years, scholars such as John Cassidy have changed the focus, finding in Marx what Eric Hobsbawm artfully described as his ‘predictions of an increasingly uncontrollable globalization of the capitalist economy.’ After all, Marx had written at the mid-point of the nineteenth century lines which would not be out of place in a newspaper column of 2013:

The need of a constantly expanding market for its products chases the bourgeoisie over the whole surface of the globe . . . The bourgeoisie has through its exploitation of the world-market given a cosmopolitan character to production and consumption in every country.

Explaining the emergence and subsequent impact of Marx’s thought, then, is no easy task for historians. It is tempting to see his ideas and writings as being the product of a particular stage in the development of European thought and culture. Clearly Capital belongs to the general historical context in which it was written – that of the Utopian Socialists, the revolutionaries of 1848 and those who invented other forms of socialism and even communism. But there is also novelty and individual genius here as well. After all, it is not only Marx’s ideas but Marx the individual who has become impressed on the modern mind. Some of that character, which this short essay has attempted to illuminate in a small way, comes through in the iconic image of Marx captured in John Mayall’s (1813–1901) penetrating photograph of 1875 (shown on page xxvii).

Many years ago, Isaiah Berlin suggested that we separate the fate of Marxism from our assessment of Marx’s thought. ‘Even if all its specific conclusions were proved false,’ Berlin wrote, ‘its importance in creating a wholly new attitude to social and historical questions and so opening new avenues of human knowledge would be unimpaired.’ David McLellan reminded us in a book about Marx’s legacy, that even if one disagrees with Marx, there is no doubt that he ‘has shaped our ideas about society. He built up a system which draws on philosophy, on history, on economics and on politics. And although the professional philosophers, the economists and the political scientists often do not accept his theories, they cannot ignore them.’ Marx has ‘become part of the mental scaffolding of the [twentieth] century with the result that a lot of our thinking about history and society is a dialogue with Marx’s ghost.’ In our century the Marxist historian Eric Hobsbawm (1917–2012) put it differently. In How to Change the World: Marx and Marxism, 18402011, one of his final publications, Hobsbawm confidently declared: ‘Economic and political liberalism, singly or in combination, cannot provide the solution to the problems of the twenty-first century. Once again the time has come to take Marx seriously.’ Regardless of how much or little truth there is in Hobsbawm’s sentiments about liberalism’s fate, there is no doubt of the continued relevance of Marx’s masterpiece, Capital, to twenty-first-century readers of today and even, we can venture with some confidence, engaged readers of tomorrow.

Mark G. Spencer

St. Catharines, Ontario, Canada

Further Reading

Althusser, Louis, and Étienne Balibar, translated by Ben Brewster. Reading ‘Capital’ (London: NLD, 1970).

Avineri, Shlomo. The Social and Political Thought of Karl Marx (London: Cambridge University Press, 1968).

Berlin, Isaiah, with a new forward by Alan Ryan. Karl Marx, His Life and Environment, 4th ed. (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996).

Bober, Mandell Morton. Karl Marx’s Interpretation of History, 2nd ed. (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1948).

Bottomore, Tom, et al., eds. A Dictionary of Marxist Thought (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1983).

Bradley, Ian, and Michael Howard, eds. Classical and Marxian Political Economy: Essays in Honor of Ronald L. Meek (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1982).

Brudney, Daniel. Marx’s Attempt to Leave Philosophy (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1998).

Buchanan, Allen E. ‘Marx, Morality, and History: An Assessment of Recent Analytical Work on Marx’, Ethics 98 (1987): 104–36.

Callinicos, Alex. The Revolutionary Ideas of Karl Marx (London: Bookmarks, 1983).

Carver, Terrell. A Marx Dictionary (Cambridge and Oxford: Polity Press,1987).

Carver, Terrell. Marx’s Social Theory (New York: Oxford University Press, 1982).

Carver, Terrell, ed., The Cambridge Companion to Marx (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991).

Cassidy, John. ‘The Return of Karl Marx’, New Yorker 73, no. 32 (20–27 October 1997): 248–259.

Cohen, G.A. Karl Marx’s Theory of History: A Defense (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1978).

Cohen, Marshall, Thomas Nagel, and Thomas Scanlon, eds., Marx, Justice, and History (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1980).

Cornu, Auguste. The Origins of Marxian Thought (Springfield, IL: Charles C. Thomas Publisher, 1957).

Elster, Jon. Making Sense of Marx (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985).

Elster, Jon. An Introduction to Karl Marx (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1986).

Gilbert, Alan. Marx’s Politics: Communists and Citizens (New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press, 1981).

Fleischer, Helmut. Marxism and History translated by Eric Mosbacher (New York: Harper Torchbooks, 1973).

Fromm, Erich. Marx’s Concept of Man (New York: Frederick Ungar Publishing, Co., 1961).

Harvey, David. A Companion to Marx’s ‘Capital’ (London and New York: Verso, 2010).

Hobsbawm, Eric J., ed. The History of Marxism. Volume One: Marxism in Marx’s Day (Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press, 1982).

Hobsbawm, Eric J. How to Change the World: Marx and Marxism, 1840–2011 (London: Little, Brown, 2011).

Hook, Sidney. Towards the Understanding of Karl Marx: A Revolutionary Interpretation (New York: John Day Co., 1933).

Hook, Sidney. From Hegel to Marx: Studies in the Intellectual Development of Karl Marx (New York: The Humanities Press, 1958).

Kolakowski, Leszek. Main Currents of Marxism : its origins, growth, and dissolution, 3 volumes, translated from the Polish by P. S. Falla (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1978).

Laski, Harold J. Karl Marx: An Essay (London: The Fabian Society and Allen & Unwin limited, 1922).

Lenin, Vladimir Ilyich. Karl Marx: A Brief Biographical Sketch with an Exposition of Marxism (1918).

Levine, Andrew. The General Will: Rousseau, Marx, Communism (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1993).

Lichtheim, George. The Origins of Socialism (New York: Praeger, 1969).

Lindsay, A. D. Karl Marx’s Capital: An Introductory Essay (London: Oxford University Press, 1925).

Little, Daniel. The Scientific Marx (Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press, 1986).

Marcuse, Herbert. Soviet Marxism: A Critical Analysis (New York: Columbia University Press, 1961).

Mazlish, Bruce. The Meaning of Karl Marx (New York: Oxford University Press, 1984).

McLellan, David. Karl Marx: His Life and Thought (New York: Harper & Row, 1973).

McLellan, David. Karl Marx: The Legacy, from the BBC TV Series written and presented by Asa Briggs (London: British Broadcasting Corporation, 1983).

McLellan, David, ed. Marx: The First Hundred Years (London: Fontana Books, 1983).

McLellan, David. The Young Hegelians and Karl Marx (London: MacMillan and Co., 1969).

McMurtry, John. The Structure of Marx’s World-View (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1978).

Meek, Ronald L. ‘The Scottish Contribution to Marxist Sociology’, in Economics and Ideology and Other Essays (London: Chapman and Hall, Ltd, 1967).

Meek, Ronald L. Studies in the Labour Theory of Value (London: Lawrence & Wishart, 1956).

Mehring, Franz. Karl Marx: The Story of His Life. Eng. trans. by Edward Fitzgerald, new introduction by Max Schachtman (Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, 1962).

Miller, Richard W. Analyzing Marx: Morality, Power and History (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1987).

Prawer, S. S. Karl Marx and World Literature (Oxford University Press, 1978).

Rader, Melvin. Marx’s Interpretation of History (New York: Oxford University Press, 1979).

Rühle, Otto. Karl Marx, His Life and Work. Eng. trans. by Eden and Cedar Paul (New York: Garden City Press, 1936).

Russell, James. Marx-Engels Dictionary (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1980).

Shipside, Steve. Karl Marx’s ‘Das Kapital’: A Modern-Day Interpretation of an Economic Classic (Oxford: Infinite Ideas Limited, 2009).

Singer, Peter. Marx (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1980).

Spencer, Mark G. ‘Introduction: Adam Smith and the Wealth of Nations’, in Adam Smith: Wealth of Nations (Ware, Hertfordshire: Wordsworth Editions, 2012).

Sperber, Jonathan. Karl Marx: A Nineteenth-Century Life (New York and London: Liverright Publishing Company, 2013).

Tucker, Robert C. Philosophy and Myth in Karl Marx, 3rd ed. (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers, 2001).

Uchida, Hiroshi, ed. Marx for the 21st Century (London and New York: Routledge, 2006).

Walker, Angus. Marx, His Theory and its Context: Politics as Economics, an introductory and critical essay on the political economy of Karl Marx (London and New York: Longman, 1978).

Wendling, Amy E. Karl Marx on Technology and Alienation (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2009).

Wheen, Francis. Karl Marx: A Life (New York and London: W. W. Norton & Company, 2000).

Wheen, Francis. Marx’s ‘Das Kapital’: A Biography (New York: Atlantic Monthly Press, 2006).

Wolff, Jonathan. Why Read Marx Today? (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002).

Wood, Allen W. Karl Marx, 2nd ed. (New York: Routledge, 2004).

Yasko, Guy. Capital in Manga! Based on the Classic Text by Karl Marx (Red Quill Books: Ottawa, 2012).

Zeitlin, Irving M. Marxism: A Re-examination (Princeton, NJ: Van Nostrand, 1967).

Typesetter’s note

In Volume 1 Marx refers to the projected later parts of the work as Books 2, 3 and 4. However, when it comes to the projected second book, he refers to it as Volume 2, and to Book 1 sometimes as Book 1 and sometimes as Volume 1. I have not corrected this inconsistency.

Within Volume 1 (and to a lesser extent Volume 2) the longest chapters are divided into sections, subsections, sub-subsections and sub-sub-subsections. These are treated in the text as follows.

Section heading: Section 1. Section Title

Subsection heading: A. Subsection Title

Sub-subsection: 1. Sub-subsection Title

Sub-sub-subsection: (a) Sub-sub-subsection Title

Capital Volume 2

Preface

It was no easy task to prepare the second volume of Capital for the printer in such a way that it should make a connected and complete work and represent exclusively the ideas of its author, not of its publisher. The great number of available manuscripts, and their fragmentary character, added to the difficulties of this task. At best one single manuscript (No. 4) had been revised throughout and made ready for the printer. And while it treated its subject-matter fully, the greater part had become obsolete through subsequent revision. The bulk of the material was not polished as to language, even if the subject-matter was for the greater part fully worked out. The language was that in which Marx used to make his outlines, that is to say his style was careless, full of colloquial, often rough and humorous, expressions and phrases, interspersed with English and French technical terms, or with whole sentences or pages of English. The thoughts were jotted down as they developed in the brain of the author. Some parts of the argument would be fully treated, others of equal importance only indicated. The material to be used for the illustration of facts would be collected, but barely arranged, much less worked out. At the conclusion of the chapters there would be only a few incoherent sentences as milestones of the incomplete deductions, showing the haste of the author in passing on to the next chapter. And finally, there was the well-known handwriting which Marx himself was sometimes unable to decipher.

I have been content to interpret these manuscripts as literally as possible, changing the style only in places where Marx would have changed it himself and interpolating explanatory sentences or connecting statements only where this was indispensable, and where the meaning was so clear that there could be no doubt of the correctness of my interpretation. Sentences which seemed in the least ambiguous were preferably reprinted literally. The passages which I have remodelled or interpolated cover barely ten pages in print, and concern mainly matters of form.

The mere enumeration of the manuscripts left by Marx as a basis for Volume 2 proves the unparalleled conscientiousness and strict self-criticism which he practised in his endeavour to fully elaborate his great economic discoveries before he published them. This self-criticism rarely permitted him to adapt his presentation of the subject, in content as well as in form, to his ever-widening horizon, which he enlarged by incessant study.

The material for this second volume consists of the following parts: First, a manuscript entitled A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy, containing 1472 quarto pages in 23 divisions, written in the time from August, 1861, to June, 1863. It is a continuation of the work of the same title, the first volume of which appeared in Berlin, in 1859. It treats on pages 1–220, and again pages 1159–1472, of the subject analysed in Volume 1 of Capital, beginning with the transformation of money into capital and continuing to the end of the volume, and is the first draft for this subject. Pages 973–1158 deal with capital and profit, rate of profit, merchant’s capital and money capital, that is to say with subjects which have been farther developed in the manuscript for Volume 3. The questions belonging to Volume 2 and many of those which are part of Volume 3 are not arranged by themselves in this manuscript. They are merely treated in passing, especially in the section which makes up the main body of the manuscript, viz. pages 220–972, entitled Theories of Surplus Value. This section contains an exhaustive critical history of the main point of political economy, the theory of surplus value, and develops at the same time, in polemic remarks against the position of the predecessors of Marx, most of the points which he has later on discussed individually and in their logical connection in Volume 2 and 3. I reserve for myself the privilege of publishing the critical part of this manuscript, after the elimination of the numerous parts covered by Volumes 2 and 3, in the form of Volume 4. This manuscript, valuable though it is, could not be used in the present edition of Volume 2.

The manuscript next following in the order of time is that of Volume 3. It was written for the greater part in 1864 and 1865. After this manuscript had been completed in its essential parts, Marx undertook the elaboration of Volume 1, which was published in 1867. I am now preparing this manuscript of Volume 3 for the printer.

The period after the publication of Volume 1, which is next in order, is represented by a collection of four manuscripts for Volume 2, marked 1–4 by Marx himself. Manuscript 1 (150 pages), presumably written in 1865 or 1867, is the first independent, but more or less fragmentary, elaboration of the questions now contained in Volume 2. This manuscript is likewise unsuited for this edition. Manuscript 2 is partly a compilation of quotations and references to the manuscripts containing Marx’s extracts and comments, most of them relating to the first section of Volume 2, partly an elaboration of special points, particularly a critique of Adam Smith’s statements as to fixed and circulating capital and the source of profits; furthermore, a discussion of the relation of the rate of surplus value to the rate of profit, which belongs in Volume 3. The references furnished little that was new, while the elaborations for Volumes 2 and 3 were rendered valueless through subsequent revisions and had to be ruled out for the greater part. Manuscript 4 is an elaboration, ready for printing, of the first section and the first chapters of the second section of Volume 2, and has been used in its proper place. Although it was found that this manuscript had been written earlier than Manuscript 2, yet it was far more finished in form and could be used with advantage for the corresponding part of this volume. I had to add only a few supplementary parts of Manuscript 2. This last manuscript is the only fairly complete elaboration of Volume 2 and dates from the year 1870. The notes for the final revision, which I shall mention immediately, say explicitly: ‘The second elaboration must be used as a basis.’

There is another interruption after 1870, due mainly to ill health. Marx employed this time in his customary way, that is to say he studied agronomics, agricultural conditions in America and especially Russia, the money market and banking institutions, and finally natural sciences, such as geology and physiology. Independent mathematical studies also form a large part of the numerous manuscripts of this period. In the beginning of 1877, Marx had recovered sufficiently to resume once more his chosen life’s work. The beginning of 1877 is marked by references and notes from the above-named four manuscripts intended for a new elaboration of Volume 2, the beginning of which is represented by Manuscript 5 (56 pages in folio). It comprises the first four chapters and is not very fully worked out. Essential points are treated in footnotes. The material is rather collected than sifted, but it is the last complete presentation of this most important first section. A preliminary attempt to prepare this part for the printer was made in Manuscript 6 (after October, 1877, and before July, 1878), embracing 17 quarto pages, the greater part of the first chapter. A second and last attempt was made in Manuscript 7, dated July 2, 1878, and consisting of 7 pages in folio.

About this time Marx seems to have realised that he would never be able to complete the second and third volume in a manner satisfactory to himself, unless a complete revolution in his health took place. Manuscripts 5–8 show traces of hard struggles against depressing physical conditions far too frequently to be ignored. The most difficult part of the first section had been worked over in Manuscript 5. The remainder of

Enjoying the preview?
Page 1 of 1